I'm sorry, but the Nobel Economic Prize from the start has less credibility than the Oscars, at least according to a excerpt from this book:
Bertrand Roehner is a Professor of Theoretical Physics at the Institute for Theoretical and High Energy
Physics at the University of Paris (Sorbonne). Dr. Roehner's main interest is interdisciplinary, particularly in
the application of physics to social phenomena. He has written several books and many articles challenging
the accepted theories concerning various social and economic events and substituting simple physical criteria.
In his 2007 book, Driving Forces in Physical, Biological and Socio−economic Phenomena: A Network
Science Investigation of Social Bonds and Interactions (Cambridge University Press), Professor Roehner
interrupts a discussion of Macro−interactions as they apply to marketing and cell phones in cars, to discuss
the Promotion of Neo−Liberalism, particularly with regard to the Nobel Prize in Economics.
Why is this a valid subject in a text that is otherwise about networks, connection schemes, and social
bonds? The simple answer is that the Nobel story is an unbelievable tale. The neo−liberaleconomists
were nothing more than a despised sect on the edges of Economic Science, unread, undistinguished, and
unknown, until a series of Nobel Prizes transformed them into the rock stars of their field, more important by
far than all competing schoolsput together. Unfortunately, Roehner detects what others have also noticed −
that the story is quite literally unbelievable. The numbers alone tell the story: 58 total laureatesfor the
Nobel Prize in Economics, of whom two thirds are from the United States (three quarters if school of
affiliation is used instead of citizenship); 8 from the Mont Pelerin society; 5 presidents of that society; 12
politically prominent neo−libs; 16 affiliated in some way with the University of Chicago & not if the
subject were cancer and the address, Love Canal, could such clustering be explained.
With meticulous attention to detail, Dr. Roehner dissects the story. He gives particular attention to the role of
the National Association of Manufacturers (NAM). Roehner features the Volker Fund and reproduces some of
the same material that we have in our accompanying article, but Roehner traces it all back even further to
the IUHEI (Institut Universitaire des Hautes Etudes Internationales) conferences organized by Rockefeller,
starting in 1927. The key role is reserved for the Mont Pelerin Society. Roehner demonstrates a pattern
whereby 5 former presidents of the Society became Nobel Prize winners shortly after ending their terms as
president.
As to how this was accomplished, Roehner traces the composition of the Nobel Committee which consisted of
5 Swedish economists. Particularly important was Erik Lundberg, the President of the Swedish Bank, who
was also a fanatical neo−lib and a leading member of the Mont Pelerin Society, and who simultaneously
served on the Nobel Committee for over a decade and was its Chairman for half that time. It was under his
term that the libertarian flood began. Lundberg was succeeded as Chairman by Assar Linbeck who had not
only been part of the Society but had collaborated with Milton Friedman. Linbeck had written a hysterical book, Turning Sweden Around, which called for slashing Sweden's social programs and the drastic privatization of state enterprises. Linbeck's co−author for that book was Torsten Persson, yet another member of the Committee destined to become its Chairman. Roehner's story details nearly endless corruption of this
sort.
The resulting critique is devastating even though it is hidden deep within the bowels of a scholarly tome about
other subjects. Professor Roehner might not voice it in the following terms, but the conclusion is inescapable:
that a bunch of mediocre balding old white men hijacked the Nobel committee for Economics and proceeded
to shamelessly give each other the Nobel Prize on ideological grounds alone (i.e., to save capitalism). Yet, despite all this, Roehner's analysis is somewhat unsatisfying. Roehner does not dwell on or perhaps is only dimly aware of the central fact which trumps all others in this story: there is no such thing as the Nobel Prize in Economics!
There never has been one. Economics was not one of the five prizes bequeathed by Alfred Nobel (Physics,
Chemistry, Literature, Peace, and Medicine), there is no mention of economicsanywhere in Alfred
Nobel's will nor in the enabling documents for the Prize when it was established in 1896, and not a nickel of
Nobel's money has ever been awarded for such a prize. So where did it come from?
In 1968, the Swedish Bank established the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of
Alfred Nobel, put up the money for the award, and talked the King of Sweden into giving away their
prizeat the same time as the Nobels. The President of the Bank, the very same Erik Lundberg discussed
above, promised a selection process and committee kinda, sorta, just like that of the realprizes,
immediately stacked the committee, and they were off to the races. In 1971, the first prize was awarded to a neo−liberal, F.A. Hayek, and the new prizebecame bathed in controversy.
The prizewas awarded jointly to Gunnar Myrdal, Sweden's most famous economist, and to Hayek. The ungrateful Myrdal immediately turned around and announced publicly that Hayek didn't deserve the prize. Oddly, Hayek agreed. Nevertheless, none of this prevented the world press from trumpeting, Universities from gushing, and Foundations from funding, the flood of new laureates, blissfully, or perhaps intentionally, unaware of the underlying fraud.
The comedy went on unhindered until Peter Nobel, the great−grandnephew of Alfred Nobel, went public with
a blistering criticism of the memorial Prize in the 1990s. The Swedish Riksbank, like a cuckoo, has
placed its egg in another very decent bird's nest. What the Bank did was akin to trademark infringement,
unacceptably robbing the real Nobel Prizes. Nobel said, 'Two thirds of these prizes in economics have gone
to US economists, particularly of the Chicago School & these have nothing to do with Alfred Nobel's goal of
improving the human condition and our survival! Indeed they are the exact opposite...'
Faced with an unwanted controversy, the Swedish Bank promised significant reformsin its selection
criteria and in the committee for the prize. The neo−liberal flood had already ended in any case. The
final irony was played out in 2001 when the reformed economics committee awarded the prize to American
Economist and Columbia Professor, Joseph Stiglitz. Stiglitz's contribution is essentially a complete refutation of the one scientific claim made by neo−liberal or Austrianeconomics: that unregulated free−markets provide the highest possible economic efficiency.
Nope. Not true. Perhaps even worse, Stiglitz mathematically and formally demonstrated the potential
efficiency−enhancing properties of the state based on the Greenwald−Stiglitz theorems (by establishing the −
constrained − Pareto inefficiency of market economies with imperfect information and incomplete markets).
In other words, big governmentisn't the problemfrom even the most elementary of economic standpoint.
It is capital and markets which contribute the fundamental inefficiencies.