Zed wrote:The entire mindset displayed in the first post presumes that if the technology for a development is present, that development will occur.
As the first poster, I feel qualified to disagree. I don't think you know what the mindset displayed in the first post was at all. You see, for me the whole point of the exercise is to figure out
why certain developments did not occur over a period of hundreds of years when the physical capability to achieve them existed or was within relatively easy reach.
That may be because the technology wasn't there after all.
It may be due to social factors, which believe it or not I did mention:
"
If it wasn't material technology that was lacking, why didn't the existing technologies merge into something like the Industrial Revolution of the early 1800s?
I mean, surely one can still ask "why not" when faced with something that, as far as we know,
could have happened but did not happen. So jumping up and down and saying "social factors meant it didn't have to happen because the conditions didn't lead to it!" is meaningless by itself.
How did conditions prevent it from happening? That's what I was asking about in the first place.
Zed wrote:I've looked up a more eloquent formulation of the point about the importance of cultural, social and economic context:
In the light of this discussion of the extent to which the conditions for economic expansion were fulfilled in ancient times it should now be possible to suggest a tentative answer to the question posed at the start of this paper. The Greeks of the classical period, it may be concluded, did perhaps have the right climate of opinion, though even this is doubtful in view of the bias against practical pursuits that was so widespread among the educated classes of society. If they did have it, it was about all they did have. For they did not have a large enough population, or the raw materials, or the sources of power to start themselves on a process of industrial expansion, and it is also very doubtful whether they had sufficient wealth for capital development. The Romans on the other hand almost certainly had the wealth, and probably a large enough population. But they lacked the right climate of opinion, and, like the Greeks, they also were short of easily available raw materials and adequate sources of energy. In these respects the Graeco-Roman world presents a marked contrast to the countries of north-western Europe where the Industrial Revolution did eventually start. For in addition to a large population and a flourishing agriculture to provide the financial basis, these countries also possessed abundant supplies of most metals and of coal, reliable water-power that could easily be exploited, and an extensive system of inland waterways to provide cheap and easy transport. But the Graeco-Roman world, lacking nearly all these advantages, was not in a position to develop itself technically. Consequently, in spite of its great achievements in literature, in the arts, and in the technique of government, it remained materially at much the same level as its predecessors, the ancient civilizations of Egypt and Mesopotamia.'
And yet much of this is a matter of
material factors, not social ones. Having a small population or a lack of coal and metal are not social factors.